WACC - APV and FTE Revisited

March 25, 2018 | Author: Joariso | Category: Cost Of Capital, Financial Economics, Money, Finance (General), Economies


Comments



Description

WACC, APV, and FTE revisitedLutz Kruschwitz and Andreas L¨offler ∗ Version: August 1998 Abstract Today, every textbook on corporate finance contains a chapter on valuation of levered firms. Typically, it is stated that the net present value of a project is exactly the same under the three methods APV, WACC, and FTE. We will show in this paper that this is wrong: in general, WACC and APV will provide necessarily different values of the firm. Furthermore, the method that can be applied depends on the underlying financing assumption of the model. It turns out that the FTE method is not a suitable approach to firm valuation. The literature states that there is a so–called circularity problem with the WACC ap- proach. We show that this problem is a fictious one. 1 Introduction Today, every textbook on corporate finance contains a chapter on valuation of levered firms. As a rule, three methods are proposed: the APV (adjusted present value) approach, the WACC (weighted average cost of capital) approach and the FTE (flow to equity) method. The APV approach essentially going back to the fundamental result of Modigliani & Miller (1958) was extended by Myers (see Myers (1974)) to normative capital budgeting analysis. The WACC approach was developed by Modigliani and Miller (see Modigliani & Miller (1963)), extended by Miles and Ezzell (see Miles & Ezzell (1980)) and recently generalized by L¨offler (see L¨ offler (1998)). Incomprehensibly, the topic is virtually not discussed in recent publications – although up to now there is no satisfying comparison of these methods. For example, it is typically stated that ”the net present value of our project is exactly the same under each of the three methods . . . However, one method usually provides an easier computation than another . . . ” (Ross et al. (1996), p. 461). We will show in this paper that this statement is wrong: in general, the APV and the WACC methods will pro- vide necessarily different values of the firm. Furthermore, the method that can be applied depends on the underlying financing assumption of the model and has nothing to do with computational considerations. In other words, WACC and APV are two completely different ways of evaluating tax savings on interest rates. ∗ Institut f¨ ur Bank– und Finanzwirtschaft der Freien Universit¨at Berlin, Boltzmannstr. 20, D–14195 Berlin. We thank Anthony F. Herbst, Edwin O. Fischer and Nichaolas Wonder for helpful remarks. 1 Kruschwitz/L¨offler WACC, APV, and FTE revisited p. 2 For this reason, we carefully analyze the underlying assumptions of both the WACC and the APV method. It turns out that we have to consider two different cases depending on whether the future value of the firm is a random variable or not. Also, the literature proposes the FTE method as an approach to valuate a levered firm. Yet, as we show, FTE needs information for valuation that is only given by WACC and APV together. Therefore we conclude that FTE is not an operationalizable approach for firm valuation. The paper is organized as follows: in the next section we state the assumptions of the model. The third section considers the case of deterministic future value of the firm. In the fourth section we analyze the case of random future value. The last section concludes the paper. 2 Assumptions of the Model If a firm is to be evaluated, one has to know what investments the managers are going to make. The investment decision will then determine the free cash flows of the firm. We will denote these cash flows at time t by CF t . Future cash flows are uncertain today, at time t = 0. We assume that the firm at time t is financed by stocks S t and bonds B t . Debt is certain. The cost of capital for debt will be denoted by r f , they remain constant through time. Furthermore, cost of capital for the common stock of an unlevered firm is given by r ∗ S and remain constant through time, too. Both assumptions are made for simplicity. The calculation can be carried out analogously if r f and r S change with time. There is an income tax, applied at rate τ, the tax rate is assumed constant. Debt reduces the taxable income base because interest payments are tax-deductible. The value of the unlevered firm is given by V u 0 = T ¸ t=1 (1 −τ)E[ CF t ] (1 +r ∗ S ) t . (1) To determine the value of the tax shield we have to consider two cases. These cases differ concerning the value of the unlevered firm V u t at t > 0: up to now we do not know whether or not it is a random variable. In the second case (the value of the firm is a random variable) the financing decision of the firm has to be considered. Consequently, WACC and APV will inevitably give different values of the firm. In the first case, however, the value of the firm is independent of the method one uses. 3 First case: V u t not a random variable We are aware of two special cases in which this assumption will hold: • If the future cash flow is constant through time the value of the unlevered firm is always V U t = (1−τ)E[ CF] r ∗ S , and this is not a random variable. 2 Kruschwitz/L¨offler WACC, APV, and FTE revisited p. 3 • If the cash flow follows a Markov process the values CF t+1 , . . . are by assumption independent of the state of the world at time t. Hence, the value of the firm V u t is also independent of the state at time t. If the value of the unlevered firm is not a random variable but deterministic today, ever- thing turns out to be simple. The firm can be evaluated depending on the data the investor knows. Since under the assumption of the case debt and equity are certain (seen from t = 0), the tax shield is certain too and has to be discounted with the cost of debt r f . Hence, the value of the levered firm is given by the theory of Modigliani and Miller (see Brealey & Myers (1996)) V l 0 = V u 0 + T−1 ¸ t=0 τr f B t (1 +r f ) t+1 . (2) If the value of the unlevered firm is not a random variable (2) gives always the correct value of the firm. According to the literature we will denote this equation by the APV approach. If an investor knows the future amount of debt B t then equation (2) already determines the value of the levered firm. But (2) cannot be applied if the investor knows only the future leverage ratio instead of the amount of debt. The leverage ratio will be denoted by l t = B t S t . (3) Since the underlying assumptions are not changed (2) still remains true. In Appendix 1 we have shown that this equation can be written as 1 V l 0 = T−1 ¸ t=1 (r f −r ∗ S )V u t + (1 +r f )(1 −τ)E[ CF t ] (1 +r ∗ S ) t−1 ¸ k=0 (1 +r k ) , (4) where r k is given by: 1 +r k = 1 +r f 1 −τ l k 1 +l k . (5) We will denote this equation as modified APV approach. We are not aware of a formulation of (5) that looks similar to the WACC equation (see (9) below). It is possible to modify equation (3) such that S 0 can be evaluated directly and this equation is denoted as FTE approach (see Brealey & Myers (1996), p.??). But to use this approach one has to know 1 If expected cash flows and the leverage ratio are constant this formula reduces to the Modigliani–Miller equation V l 0 = V u 0 r ∗ S 1 −τ l 1+l . 3 Kruschwitz/L¨offler WACC, APV, and FTE revisited p. 4 1. the expected cash–flows after taxes and interest, hence the amount of future debt B t and 2. the cost of capital for stocks. The cost of capital can be derived from the textbook formula (see for example Brealey & Myers (1996), p.??) if one knows the future leverage ratio l t . As can be seen, the application of FTE presupposes the information provided by WACC and modified APV together. Since the result is the same, there is no reason to use the FTE approach. To summarize: if the value of the unlevered firm is not a random variable, one can use the APV approach (2) to determine the value of the levered firm. If the future amount of debt is not known but the leverage ratio is known, one can modify the APV approach to an equation that still determines the firm’s value. And both equations yield the same value. There is no need to apply the FTE approach. 4 Second case: V u t a random variable We will now assume that the value of the unlevered firm at time t is a random variable. We believe that this assumption is (in contrast to section 3) the more realistic case. What are the consequences for the APV and the WACC approach? In the last section both debt and the leverage ratio were deterministic. If V U t is a random variable, the story is more complicated. We will illustrate that by means of an example. Consider a model with two periods. It is assumed that the firm will be liquidated at the end of period two. CF 2 is the cash flow of the firm at time t = 2. The owner receives the after–tax–cash flow (dividend) ¯ D 2 . r S are the cost of capital for equity in the levered firm. Since the firm will be liquidated at time t = 2, and interest payments reduce the tax base, we have ¯ D 2 = E[(1 −τ) CF 2 | F 1 ] − (1 +r f (1 −τ))B 1 . Therefore, equity at time t = 1 has the value ¯ S 1 = E[ ¯ D 2 | F 1 ] 1 +r S . Now assume, the dividend policy of the firm is determined at time t = 0. This is to say that the amount of debt at time t = 1 is already known at t = 0 and is not a random variable. Therefore, we can evaluate the leverage ratio at t = 1 ¯ l 1 = B 1 ¯ S 1 = B 1 (1 +r S ) E[(1 −τ) CF 2 | F 1 ] − (1 +r f (1 −τ))B 1 . (6) Now, particularly since the amount of debt is deterministic, the leverage ratio at time t = 1 becomes a random variable! Hence, with a given dividend policy the leverage policy will be prescribed and not deterministic. 4 Kruschwitz/L¨offler WACC, APV, and FTE revisited p. 5 Vice versa, if we lay down the leverage ratio at time t = 1 to be determined at t = 0 the dividend policy is already specified. To prove this rearrange (6) and get ¯ B 1 = l 1 E[(1 −τ) CF 2 | F 1 ] 1 +r S +l 1 (1 +r f (1 −τ)) . (7) (7) shows that a deterministic leverage ratio will yield a random dividend policy. We sum- marize our interim results as follows. finance policy dividend policy leverage policy B t deterministic l t deterministic l t random variable B t random variable =⇒ certain tax shield =⇒ uncertain tax shield This reveals that the investor has to make a decision about financing policy: There is a considerable difference between determining the dividend versus the leverage policy. Hence, we will expect two different values of the firm according to the financing policy that will be followed. We consider the two policies separately. 4.1 Deterministic debt or the APV method Throughout this section we assume that future debt of the firm is deterministic. As we have seen already, the future leverage ratio of the firm will then be a random variable. The theory of Modigliani and Miller now implies that the tax shield will be deterministic and therefore certain. Consequently, the cost of capital for the tax shield is r f . Suppose that the investor knows the future amount of debt B t . As we have mentioned in the preceding section, the value of the firm is given by the APV method: V L 0 = V U 0 + T−1 ¸ t=0 τr f B t (1 +r f ) t+1 . (8) What happens if the investor does not know the future amount of debt but instead the expected leverage ratios (remember that the leverage ratios are uncertain)? Is it still possible to value the firm using this information? Since the underlying assumptions of the model do not change, equation (8) still remains true. The question is whether it is possible to evaluate the future amount of debt by knowing only the expected leverage ratios. Equation (8) should then be transformed such that it contains the expected leverage ratios E[ ˜ l t ]. We will now show that such a transformation is impossible. We illustrate that with a simple example which shows that the knowledge of the expected leverage ratios does not suffice to value the firm if the future amount of debt is certain. Consider again equation (6) E[ ¯ l 1 ] = E ¸ B 1 (1 +r S ) E[(1 −τ) CF 2 | F 1 ] − (1 +r f (1 −τ))B 1 ¸ . 5 Kruschwitz/L¨offler WACC, APV, and FTE revisited p. 6 At first, it is easy to see that (given the expected leverage ratio) a unique solution of the amount of debt exists: if B 1 = 0 then the right hand side of the equation is zero. If B 1 increases, the right hand sides strictly increases. Hence, there must be a unique B 1 such that the right hand side equals the expected leverage ratio. But there does not necessarily exist a formula to determine B 1 . Consider the case where the conditional expectation of future cash flow E[ CF 2 | F 1 ] has two realisations CF 2,1 and CF 2,1 with probabilities p 1 and p 2 . Then (6) can be written as E[ ¯ l 1 ] = p 1 B 1 (1 +r S ) (1 −τ)CF 2,1 − (1 +r f (1 −τ))B 1 +p 2 B 1 (1 +r S ) (1 −τ)CF 2,2 − (1 +r f (1 −τ))B 1 , and we can calculate B 1 by solving a quadratic equation. But if the conditional expectation of future cash flow has n realisations, this leads us to a polynomial of degree n and there does not exist a closed form solution for such a polynomial in general. To summarize: If the future amount of debt is deterministic and known, then the APV method gives the correct value of the firm. If only the expected leverage ratios are known, APV is still the right method but there does not exist a formula involving E[ ¯ l t ] to determine the value of the firm. 4.2 Deterministic leverage ratio or the WACC method We will now assume that the leverage ratio is determined at time t = 0. This implies that the tax shield is not certain and therefore cannot be discounted at r f . Equation (8) does not yield the correct value of the firm: “Even though the firm might issue riskless debt, if financing policy is targeted to realized market values, the amount of debt outstanding in future periods is not known with certainty (unless the investment is riskless) . . . ” Miles & Ezzell (1980), p. 721. In this case Modigliani & Miller (1963) developed a theory for the case of a perpetual cash flow. This approach was later generalized by Miles & Ezzell (1980) to the case of a constant leverage ratio. L¨ offler (1998) recently proved a general WACC formula that is already applicable if the leverage ratio is deterministic. The main part of the proof was to show that the correct cost of capital for the tax shield is r ∗ S , the cost of capital of the unlevered firm. Suppose, the investor knows the future leverage ratios of the firm. As was shown in L¨ offler (1998), the value of the firm is given by the WACC method V L 0 = T ¸ t=1 (1 −τ)E[ CF t ] ¸ t−1 k=0 (1 − τr f 1+r f l k )(1 +r ∗ S ) . (9) What happens if the investor knows the expected amount of debt in future periods? Since the underlying assumptions do not change, equation (9) still determines the correct value of 6 Kruschwitz/L¨offler WACC, APV, and FTE revisited p. 7 the firm. But this equation has to be modified to include E[ ˜ B t ]. In appendix 2 we show that the value of the firm is now given by the equation V L 0 = V U 0 + T−1 ¸ t=0 τr f E[ ˜ B t ] (1 +r ∗ S ) t · (1 +r f ) . (10) As one can see, the difference of this modified APV–equation compared to equation (8) is the cost of capital for the tax shield. Ususally, the literature states that there is a theoretical problem with the WACC approach (the so–called circularity problem): “To calculate the changing WACC, one must know the market value of a firm’s debt and equity. But if the debt and equity values are already known, the total market value of the company is also known. That is, one must know the value of the company to calculate the WACC” Ross et al. (1996), p.480. As we have shown the WACC method can only be applied • if the future leverage ratios are deterministic and • if these ratios are known. In this case there does not exist any circularity problem. In all other cases however, WACC is not applicable. The circularity problem is a fictious one. What can be said about the FTE approach? First, since FTE uses the textbook formula, the underlying assumption has to be the same as in the WACC method: a deterministic leverage ratio. Similarly to the case of certain V u t one then has to know 1. the expected cash–flows after taxes and interest and hence the expected amount of future debt and 2. the cost of capital for stocks. The cost of capital can be derived via the textbook formula if one knows the future leverage ratio. Again, the application of FTE presupposes the information provided by WACC. Since the result is the same, there is no reason to use the FTE approach, one can instead use WACC. To summarize: if the value of the unlevered firm is not a random variable, one can use the APV approach (2) to determine the value of the levered firm. If the future amount of debt is not known but the leverage ratio is known, one can modify the APV approach to an equation that still determines the firm’s value. And both equations yield the same value. The FTE approach is not an operationalizable method for firm valuation. 5 Summary We have analyzed the underlying assumptions of the WACC and the APV approach. We have shown that WACC can only be applied if the leverage ratio of the company is deterministic 7 Kruschwitz/L¨offler WACC, APV, and FTE revisited p. 8 and known at time t = 0. APV can be used to evaluate the firm if the amount of future debt is deterministic and known today. Since both methods use different assumptions on the financing decision of the firm, one cannot expect the same value by WACC and APV. The FTE approach is not a suitable method for firm valuation. We summarize our results as follow: finance information assumptions B t (or E[B t ]) known l t (or E[l t ]) known B t deterministic APV method (8) no formula l t deterministic mod. APV method (10) WACC method (9) Appendix 1 To prove (4) we assume the following equations. The value of the levered firm at time t is given by the value of the unlevered firm V u t and the value of the tax shield T t : V l t = V u t +T t . (11) Since the cost of capital for the unlevered firm remain constant we have V u t = V u t+1 + (1 −τ)E[ CF t+1 ] 1 +r ∗ S . (12) The APV method implies the following iteration for the tax shield T t = T t+1 1 +r f + τr f 1 +r f B t . (13) From (11), (12) and (13) we get using the definition of the leverage ratio l t V l t = V u t+1 + E[ CF t+1 ] 1 +r ∗ S + T t+1 +τr f l t 1+l t V l t 1 +r f . Rearranging this equation gives 1 − τr f 1 +r f l t 1 +l t V l t = V u t+1 + E[ CF t+1 ] 1 +r ∗ S + T t+1 1 +r f = V u t+1 + E[ CF t+1 ] 1 +r ∗ S + V l t+1 −V u t+1 1 +r f = V u t+1 (r f −r ∗ S ) (1 +r ∗ S )(1 +r f ) + E[ CF t+1 ] 1 +r ∗ S + V l t+1 1 +r f 1 +r f −τr f l t 1 +l t V l t = V u t+1 (r f −r ∗ S ) 1 +r ∗ S + 1 +r f 1 +r ∗ S E[ CF t+1 ] +V l t+1 V l t = V u t+1 (r f −r ∗ S ) (1 +r ∗ S )(1 +r f (1 −τ l t 1+l t )) + + E[ CF t+1 ](1 +r f ) (1 +r ∗ S )(1 +r f (1 −τ l t 1+l t )) + V l t+1 1 +r f (1 −τ l t 1+l t ) 8 Kruschwitz/L¨offler WACC, APV, and FTE revisited p. 9 By applying this iteration we show that (4) is indeed a consequence. Using (5) we get V l T−1 = E[ CF T ](1 +r f ) (1 +r ∗ S )(1 +r T−1 ) . At time T − 2 we have for the value of the firm V l T−2 = V u T−1 (r f −r ∗ S ) (1 +r ∗ S )(1 +r T−2 ) + E[ CF T−1 ](1 +r f ) (1 +r ∗ S )(1 +r T−2 ) + E[ CF T ](1 +r f ) (1 +r ∗ S )(1 +r T−1 )(1 +r T−2 ) . At T − 3 we have V l T−3 = V u T−2 (r f −r ∗ S ) (1 +r ∗ S )(1 +r T−3 ) + V u T−1 (r f −r ∗ S ) (1 +r ∗ S )(1 +r T−2 )(1 +r T−3 ) + + E[ CF T−2 ](1 +r f ) (1 +r ∗ S )(1 +r T−3 ) + E[ CF] T−1 ](1 +r f ) (1 +r ∗ S )(1 +r T−2 )(1 +r T−3 ) + + E[ CF T ](1 +r f ) (1 +r ∗ S )(1 +r T−1 )(1 +r T−2 )(1 +r T−3 ) . (14) As one can see, (4) indeed determines the value of the levered firm at time t = 0. Appendix 2 We assume that the leverage ratio is deterministic but unkown to the investor. Instead the investor knows the expected amount of debt E[ ˜ B t ]. We follow the theory in L¨ offler (1998) and know that the value of the levered firm is given by the value of the unlevered firm and the value of the tax shield V l 0 = V u 0 +T 0 . This (uncertain) tax shield satisfies the following iteration T t = E[T t+1 | F t ] 1 +r ∗ S + τr f F t 1 +r f . Using the law of iterated expectation t < s =⇒ E[[X | F s ] | F t ] = E[X | F t ] we get for the tax shield at time t = 0 T 0 = T−1 ¸ t=0 τr f E[ ˜ B t ] (1 +r ∗ S ) t · (1 +r f ) and therefore the assertion. 9 Kruschwitz/L¨offler WACC, APV, and FTE revisited p. 10 References Brealey, R.A., & Myers, St.C. (1996). Principles of Corporate Finance. 5. edn. New York: Wiley & Sons. L¨ offler, A. (1998). WACC–approach and nonconstant leverage ratio. unpublished, Berlin. URL: http://www.wiwiss.fu-berlin.de/w3/w3krusch/pub/ertrag.htm. Miles, J.A., & Ezzell, J.R. (1980). The Weighted Average Cost of Capital, Perfect Capital Markets, And Project Life: A Clarification. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 15, 719–730. Modigliani, F., & Miller, M.H. (1958). The Cost of Capital, Corporation Finance and the Theory of Investment. American Economic Review, 48, 261–297. Modigliani, F., & Miller, M.H. (1963). Corporate Income Taxes and Cost of Capital: A Correction. American Economic Review, 53, 433–443. Myers, S.C. (1974). Interactions of Corporate Financing and Investment Decisions – Impli- cations for Capital Budgeting. Journal of Finance, 29, 1–25. Ross, S.M., Westerfield, R.W., & Jaffe, J.E. (1996). Corporate Finance. 4th edn. Chicago: McGraw–Hill, Inc. 10 however. FTE needs information for valuation that is only given by WACC and APV together. Debt is certain. cost of capital for the common stock of an unlevered firm is given by ∗ rS and remain constant through time. The investment decision will then determine the free cash flows of the firm. Also. too. 3 First case: Vtu not a random variable We are aware of two special cases in which this assumption will hold: • If the future cash flow is constant through time the value of the unlevered firm is always VtU = (1−τ )E[CF] . at time t = 0. The calculation can be carried out analogously if rf and rS change with time. The third section considers the case of deterministic future value of the firm. Therefore we conclude that FTE is not an operationalizable approach for firm valuation. they remain constant through time. In the first case. the value of the firm is independent of the method one uses. It turns out that we have to consider two different cases depending on whether the future value of the firm is a random variable or not. Debt reduces the taxable income base because interest payments are tax-deductible. We will denote these cash flows at time t by CFt . the literature proposes the FTE method as an approach to valuate a levered firm. WACC and APV will inevitably give different values of the firm.Kruschwitz/L¨ffler o WACC. 2 . Future cash flows are uncertain today. These cases differ concerning the value of the unlevered firm Vtu at t > 0: up to now we do not know whether or not it is a random variable. We assume that the firm at time t is financed by stocks St and bonds Bt . ∗ rS and this is not a random variable. applied at rate τ . one has to know what investments the managers are going to make. we carefully analyze the underlying assumptions of both the WACC and the APV method. 2 Assumptions of the Model If a firm is to be evaluated. There is an income tax. The last section concludes the paper. as we show. Furthermore. The value of the unlevered firm is given by T V0u = t=1 (1 − τ )E[CFt ] . Consequently. APV. Both assumptions are made for simplicity. Yet. 2 For this reason. and FTE revisited p. the tax rate is assumed constant. In the fourth section we analyze the case of random future value. In the second case (the value of the firm is a random variable) the financing decision of the firm has to be considered. ∗ (1 + rS )t (1) To determine the value of the tax shield we have to consider two cases. The paper is organized as follows: in the next section we state the assumptions of the model. The cost of capital for debt will be denoted by rf . In Appendix 1 we have shown that this equation can be written as1 T −1 V0l = t=1 ∗ (rf − rS )Vtu + (1 + rf )(1 − τ )E[CFt ] (1 + ∗ rS ) t−1 .??). are by assumption independent of the state of the world at time t. the value of the levered firm is given by the theory of Modigliani and Miller (see Brealey & Myers (1996)) T −1 V0l = V0u + t=0 τ rf Bt . 3 • If the cash flow follows a Markov process the values CFt+1 . We are not aware of a formulation of (5) that looks similar to the WACC equation (see (9) below). . According to the literature we will denote this equation by the APV approach. and FTE revisited p. If the value of the unlevered firm is not a random variable but deterministic today. But to use this approach one has to know If expected cash flows and the leverage ratio are constant this formula reduces to the Modigliani–Miller equation V0l = V0u l ∗ rS 1 − τ 1+l 1 . (1 + rf )t+1 (2) If the value of the unlevered firm is not a random variable (2) gives always the correct value of the firm. But (2) cannot be applied if the investor knows only the future leverage ratio instead of the amount of debt. the tax shield is certain too and has to be discounted with the cost of debt rf . (4) (1 + rk ) k=0 where rk is given by: 1 + rk = 1 + rf 1−τ lk 1 + lk . the value of the firm Vtu is also independent of the state at time t. .Kruschwitz/L¨ffler o WACC. The leverage ratio will be denoted by lt = Bt . Hence. (5) We will denote this equation as modified APV approach. . If an investor knows the future amount of debt Bt then equation (2) already determines the value of the levered firm. 3 . The firm can be evaluated depending on the data the investor knows. Hence. St (3) Since the underlying assumptions are not changed (2) still remains true. everthing turns out to be simple. p. APV. Since under the assumption of the case debt and equity are certain (seen from t = 0). It is possible to modify equation (3) such that S0 can be evaluated directly and this equation is denoted as FTE approach (see Brealey & Myers (1996). Therefore. There is no need to apply the FTE approach. we can evaluate the leverage ratio at t = 1 l1 = B1 S1 = B1 (1 + rS ) E[(1 − τ )CF2 | F1 ] − (1 + rf (1 − τ ))B1 . If the future amount of debt is not known but the leverage ratio is known. hence the amount of future debt Bt and 2. one can use the APV approach (2) to determine the value of the levered firm. And both equations yield the same value. the cost of capital for stocks.??) if one knows the future leverage ratio lt . Since the firm will be liquidated at time t = 2. APV. equity at time t = 1 has the value S1 = E[D2 | F1 ] . Consider a model with two periods. and interest payments reduce the tax base. The cost of capital can be derived from the textbook formula (see for example Brealey & Myers (1996). Since the result is the same. the story is more complicated. This is to say that the amount of debt at time t = 1 is already known at t = 0 and is not a random variable. the application of FTE presupposes the information provided by WACC and modified APV together. As can be seen. 1 + rS Now assume. with a given dividend policy the leverage policy will be prescribed and not deterministic. there is no reason to use the FTE approach. particularly since the amount of debt is deterministic. CF2 is the cash flow of the firm at time t = 2. To summarize: if the value of the unlevered firm is not a random variable. 4 . the expected cash–flows after taxes and interest. The owner receives the after–tax–cash flow (dividend) D2 . p. one can modify the APV approach to an equation that still determines the firm’s value. We will illustrate that by means of an example. If VtU is a random variable. rS are the cost of capital for equity in the levered firm. the leverage ratio at time t = 1 becomes a random variable! Hence. We believe that this assumption is (in contrast to section 3) the more realistic case. What are the consequences for the APV and the WACC approach? In the last section both debt and the leverage ratio were deterministic. we have D2 = E[(1 − τ )CF2 | F1 ] − (1 + rf (1 − τ ))B1 . the dividend policy of the firm is determined at time t = 0. It is assumed that the firm will be liquidated at the end of period two. 4 Second case: Vtu a random variable We will now assume that the value of the unlevered firm at time t is a random variable. (6) Now.Kruschwitz/L¨ffler o WACC. 4 1. and FTE revisited p. Therefore. 1 Deterministic debt or the APV method Throughout this section we assume that future debt of the firm is deterministic. Consequently. As we have mentioned in the preceding section. and FTE revisited p. l We will now show that such a transformation is impossible. APV. We illustrate that with a simple example which shows that the knowledge of the expected leverage ratios does not suffice to value the firm if the future amount of debt is certain. Suppose that the investor knows the future amount of debt Bt . 1 + rS + l1 (1 + rf (1 − τ )) (7) (7) shows that a deterministic leverage ratio will yield a random dividend policy. We consider the two policies separately. As we have seen already. The theory of Modigliani and Miller now implies that the tax shield will be deterministic and therefore certain. The question is whether it is possible to evaluate the future amount of debt by knowing only the expected leverage ratios. the cost of capital for the tax shield is rf . Hence. 5 Vice versa. the future leverage ratio of the firm will then be a random variable. (1 + rf )t+1 (8) What happens if the investor does not know the future amount of debt but instead the expected leverage ratios (remember that the leverage ratios are uncertain)? Is it still possible to value the firm using this information? Since the underlying assumptions of the model do not change. if we lay down the leverage ratio at time t = 1 to be determined at t = 0 the dividend policy is already specified. equation (8) still remains true. To prove this rearrange (6) and get B1 = l1 E[(1 − τ )CF2 | F1 ] . .Kruschwitz/L¨ffler o WACC. the value of the firm is given by the APV method: T −1 V0L = V0U + t=0 τ rf Bt . 4. finance policy dividend policy leverage policy Bt deterministic lt deterministic lt random variable Bt random variable =⇒ certain tax shield =⇒ uncertain tax shield This reveals that the investor has to make a decision about financing policy: There is a considerable difference between determining the dividend versus the leverage policy. we will expect two different values of the firm according to the financing policy that will be followed. Equation (8) should then be transformed such that it contains the expected leverage ratios E[˜t ]. Consider again equation (6) E[l1 ] = E B1 (1 + rS ) E[(1 − τ )CF2 | F1 ] − (1 + rf (1 − τ ))B1 5 . We summarize our interim results as follows. To summarize: If the future amount of debt is deterministic and known. In this case Modigliani & Miller (1963) developed a theory for the case of a perpetual cash flow. the amount of debt outstanding in future periods is not known with certainty (unless the investment is riskless) . then the APV method gives the correct value of the firm. Equation (8) does not yield the correct value of the firm: “Even though the firm might issue riskless debt. if financing policy is targeted to realized market values. If only the expected leverage ratios are known. Suppose. 4. Then (6) can be written as E[l1 ] = p1 B1 (1 + rS ) B1 (1 + rS ) + p2 . APV is still the right method but there does not exist a formula involving E[lt ] to determine the value of the firm. ” Miles & Ezzell (1980). the investor knows the future leverage ratios of the firm. This implies that the tax shield is not certain and therefore cannot be discounted at rf .2 − (1 + rf (1 − τ ))B1 and we can calculate B1 by solving a quadratic equation. the cost of capital of the unlevered firm. p.1 with probabilities p1 and p2 . the right hand sides strictly increases. and FTE revisited p. APV. Hence.1 − (1 + rf (1 − τ ))B1 (1 − τ )CF2. This approach was later generalized by Miles & Ezzell (1980) to the case of ¨ a constant leverage ratio. 721. If B1 increases.Kruschwitz/L¨ffler o WACC. (1 − τ )CF2. As was shown in ¨ Loffler (1998). 6 At first. But there does not necessarily exist a formula to determine B1 . . (9) What happens if the investor knows the expected amount of debt in future periods? Since the underlying assumptions do not change. equation (9) still determines the correct value of 6 . Loffler (1998) recently proved a general WACC formula that is already applicable if the leverage ratio is deterministic. this leads us to a polynomial of degree n and there does not exist a closed form solution for such a polynomial in general. it is easy to see that (given the expected leverage ratio) a unique solution of the amount of debt exists: if B1 = 0 then the right hand side of the equation is zero. The main part of the proof was ∗ to show that the correct cost of capital for the tax shield is rS . . But if the conditional expectation of future cash flow has n realisations. Consider the case where the conditional expectation of future cash flow E[CF2 | F1 ] has two realisations CF2.1 and CF2.2 Deterministic leverage ratio or the WACC method We will now assume that the leverage ratio is determined at time t = 0. there must be a unique B1 such that the right hand side equals the expected leverage ratio. the value of the firm is given by the WACC method T V0L = t=1 (1 − τ )E[CFt ] t−1 k=0 (1 − τ rf 1+rf lk )(1 ∗ + rS ) . In all other cases however. p. there is no reason to use the FTE approach. In appendix 2 we show that the value of the firm is now given by the equation T −1 V0L = V0U + t=0 ˜ τ rf E[Bt ] . one can modify the APV approach to an equation that still determines the firm’s value.Kruschwitz/L¨ffler o WACC. In this case there does not exist any circularity problem. and FTE revisited p.480. WACC is not applicable. the difference of this modified APV–equation compared to equation (8) is the cost of capital for the tax shield. the literature states that there is a theoretical problem with the WACC approach (the so–called circularity problem): “To calculate the changing WACC. Similarly to the case of certain Vtu one then has to know 1. If the future amount of debt is not known but the leverage ratio is known. As we have shown the WACC method can only be applied • if the future leverage ratios are deterministic and • if these ratios are known. Since the result is the same. The cost of capital can be derived via the textbook formula if one knows the future leverage ratio. since FTE uses the textbook formula. To summarize: if the value of the unlevered firm is not a random variable. (1996). And both equations yield the same value. But this equation has to be modified to include E[Bt ]. We have shown that WACC can only be applied if the leverage ratio of the company is deterministic 7 . the underlying assumption has to be the same as in the WACC method: a deterministic leverage ratio. The FTE approach is not an operationalizable method for firm valuation. one can use the APV approach (2) to determine the value of the levered firm. The circularity problem is a fictious one. APV. the application of FTE presupposes the information provided by WACC. But if the debt and equity values are already known. ∗ (1 + rS )t · (1 + rf ) (10) As one can see. That is. 7 ˜ the firm. the total market value of the company is also known. the cost of capital for stocks. one must know the market value of a firm’s debt and equity. 5 Summary We have analyzed the underlying assumptions of the WACC and the APV approach. the expected cash–flows after taxes and interest and hence the expected amount of future debt and 2. Ususally. Again. What can be said about the FTE approach? First. one can instead use WACC. one must know the value of the company to calculate the WACC” Ross et al. ∗ 1 + rS (11) (12) The APV method implies the following iteration for the tax shield τ rf Tt+1 Tt = + Bt . Since the cost of capital for the unlevered firm remain constant we have Vtu = u Vt+1 + (1 − τ )E[CFt+1 ] . The value of the levered firm at time t is given by the value of the unlevered firm Vtu and the value of the tax shield Tt : Vtl = Vtu + Tt . Since both methods use different assumptions on the financing decision of the firm.Kruschwitz/L¨ffler o WACC. 1 + rf 1 + rf From (11). We summarize our results as follow: finance assumptions Bt deterministic lt deterministic information Bt (or E[Bt ]) known lt (or E[lt ]) known APV method (8) no formula mod. (12) and (13) we get using the definition of the leverage ratio lt Vtl lt u Vt+1 + E[CFt+1 ] Tt+1 + τ rf 1+lt Vtl + . = ∗ 1 + rS 1 + rf (13) Rearranging this equation gives 1− τ rf lt 1 + rf 1 + lt Vtl = = = 1 + rf − τ rf lt 1 + lt Vtl = Vtl = u Vt+1 + E[CFt+1 ] Tt+1 + ∗ 1 + rS 1 + rf l u u Vt+1 + E[CFt+1 ] Vt+1 − Vt+1 + ∗ 1 + rS 1 + rf u ∗ Vl Vt+1 (rf − rS ) E[CFt+1 ] + t+1 + ∗ ∗ (1 + rS )(1 + rf ) 1 + rS 1 + rf u (r − r ∗ ) Vt+1 f 1 + rf S l + ∗ ∗ E[CFt+1 ] + Vt+1 1 + rS 1 + rS u ∗ Vt+1 (rf − rS ) + lt ∗ (1 + rS )(1 + rf (1 − τ 1+lt )) + l Vt+1 E[CFt+1 ](1 + rf ) + lt lt ∗ (1 + rS )(1 + rf (1 − τ 1+lt )) 1 + rf (1 − τ 1+lt ) 8 . APV can be used to evaluate the firm if the amount of future debt is deterministic and known today. and FTE revisited p. one cannot expect the same value by WACC and APV. The FTE approach is not a suitable method for firm valuation. APV. APV method (10) WACC method (9) Appendix 1 To prove (4) we assume the following equations. 8 and known at time t = 0. and FTE revisited p. (14) + rT −1 )(1 + rT −2 )(1 + rT −3 ) As one can see. This (uncertain) tax shield satisfies the following iteration Tt = Using the law of iterated expectation t<s =⇒ E[[X | Fs ] | Ft ] = E[X | Ft ] τ r f Ft E[Tt+1 | Ft ] + . Using (5) we get l VT −1 = E[CFT ](1 + rf ) . 9 . ¨ We follow the theory in Loffler (1998) and know that the value of the levered firm is given by the value of the unlevered firm and the value of the tax shield V0l = V0u + T0 . Appendix 2 We assume that the leverage ratio is deterministic but unkown to the investor. APV. Instead the ˜ investor knows the expected amount of debt E[Bt ]. 9 By applying this iteration we show that (4) is indeed a consequence. ∗ )(1 + r ∗ )(1 + r ∗ )(1 + r (1 + rS (1 + rS (1 + rS T −2 ) T −2 ) T −1 )(1 + rT −2 ) At T − 3 we have l VT −3 = u ∗ u ∗ VT −2 (rf − rS ) VT −1 (rf − rS ) + + ∗ ∗ (1 + rS )(1 + rT −3 ) (1 + rS )(1 + rT −2 )(1 + rT −3 ) + E[CFT −2 ](1 + rf ) E[CF]T −1 ](1 + rf ) + + ∗ ∗ (1 + rS )(1 + rT −3 ) (1 + rS )(1 + rT −2 )(1 + rT −3 ) + (1 + ∗ rS )(1 E[CFT ](1 + rf ) . ∗ 1 + rS 1 + rf we get for the tax shield at time t = 0 T −1 T0 = t=0 ˜ τ rf E[Bt ] ∗ (1 + rS )t · (1 + rf ) and therefore the assertion. (4) indeed determines the value of the levered firm at time t = 0.Kruschwitz/L¨ffler o WACC. ∗ (1 + rS )(1 + rT −1 ) At time T − 2 we have for the value of the firm l VT −2 = u ∗ VT −1 (rf − rS ) E[CFT −1 ](1 + rf ) E[CFT ](1 + rf ) + + . H. (1974). Interactions of Corporate Financing and Investment Decisions – Implications for Capital Budgeting. Corporate Finance. 433–443. Journal of Finance. Myers. (1958). 48. Chicago: McGraw–Hill. S. R.htm.A. Modigliani. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis.. APV. 719–730.R.E. Berlin. The Cost of Capital. (1996). New York: Wiley & Sons.C. URL: http://www. & Myers. 29. St. 261–297. (1996). Inc. 10 References Brealey.de/w3/w3krusch/pub/ertrag.W. R.A. M. (1980). & Miller. A.Kruschwitz/L¨ffler o WACC. J. ¨ Loffler. 53.. WACC–approach and nonconstant leverage ratio. Corporation Finance and the Theory of Investment.. American Economic Review. 15. Principles of Corporate Finance. F. Perfect Capital Markets..M. 10 . F. unpublished. Westerfield.wiwiss.. Corporate Income Taxes and Cost of Capital: A Correction. and FTE revisited p.H. S. Miles. edn. The Weighted Average Cost of Capital. & Jaffe. (1998). American Economic Review. 1–25.fu-berlin. Ross.. Modigliani. (1963). 4th edn. J. & Ezzell.C. & Miller. And Project Life: A Clarification. M. J. 5.
Copyright © 2024 DOKUMEN.SITE Inc.