Description

Journal of Banking & Finance 21 (1997) 1743±1759Modern portfolio theory, 1950 to date Edwin J. Elton a, Martin J. Gruber a b,* Management Education Center, 44 West 4th Street, Suite 9-190, Stern School of Business, New York, NY 10012-1126, USA b Department of Finance, Stern School of Business, New York University, Suite 9-190, 44 West 4th Street, New York, NY 10012-1126, USA Abstract In this article we have reviewed ``Modern Portfolio Analysis'' and outlined some important topics for further research. Issues discussed include the history and future of portfolio theory, the key inputs necessary to perform portfolio optimization, speci®c problems in applying portfolio theory to ®nancial institutions, and the methods for evaluating how well portfolios are managed. Emphasis is placed on both the history of major concepts and where further research is needed in each of these areas. Ó 1997 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved. JEL classi®cation: G11; G12 Keywords: Portfolio theory; Optimization; Performance evaluation; Financial institutions 1. Introduction One of the key issues facing an individual is how to allocate wealth among alternative assets. Almost all ®nancial institutions have the same problem with the added complication that they need to explicitly include the characteristics * Corresponding author. Tel.: 1 212 998 0333; fax: 1 212 995 4321; e-mail: [email protected]. 0378-4266/97/$17.00 Ó 1997 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved. PII S 0 3 7 8 - 4 2 6 6 ( 9 7 ) 0 0 0 4 8 - 4 good review articles such as Constantinides and Malliaris (1995) exist. we will discuss what we ®nd of special interest and importance.J. we will be more selective and our discussion will be rather eclectic. 1 There are also good reviews in more advanced doctoral-level texts such as Ingersoll (1987) or Huang and Litzenberger (1988). 1980). 2 Section 5 will review portfolio evaluation techniques. Historical development and current state of theory Markowitz (1952.J. Portfolio theory is a well-developed paradigm. Furthermore. chs. Section 3 discusses issues in estimating the key inputs for portfolio theory and Section 4 discusses the special issues that arise when portfolio theory is applied to ®nancial institutions. While the structure of these problems varies somewhat. The book was ®lled with insights and suggestions that anticipated many of the subsequent developments in the ®eld. taking these co-movements into account resulted in an ability to construct a 1 2 Elton and Gruber (1995). This paper is divided into four sections. namely holding constant variance. Section 2 presents a historical review of the basic theory and its current state of development. an investor had to consider how each security co-moved with all other securities. depending on individual risk return preferences. He proved the fundamental theorem of mean variance portfolio theory. they are similar enough that we classify both as portfolio theory. Rather.1744 E. 16. modern portfolio theory. FiÈ nally. 15. There are also some careful mathematical treatments (Szego. There are excellent textbooks on the subject. È . 2. Rather than attempting to survey all articles or all issues on each topic. each covering one topic. 1959) is the father of modern portfolio theory. These two principles led to the formulation of an ecient frontier from which the investor could choose his or her preferred portfolio. Elton. His original book and article on the subject clearly delineated. M. maximize expected return. This paper will present four topics we ®nd of particular interest. and holding constant expected return minimize variance. we are especially partial to our own Modern Portfolio Theory and Investment Analysis. We will attempt to convey where the ®eld is today and where it is headed in the future. for the ®rst time. The important message of the theory was that assets could not be selected only on characteristics that were unique to the security. One of the early discussions of this problem is presented by Szego (1980). Therefore. Gruber / Journal of Banking & Finance 21 (1997) 1743±1759 of their liabilities in the analysis. Of course. Markowitz formulated the portfolio problem as a choice of the mean and variance of a portfolio of assets. instead of writing one more general review article. Considering just the mean return and variance of return of a portfolio is. This persistence is not due to the realism of the utility or return distribution assumptions that are necessary for it to be correct. which have been developed based on mean variance analyses. Second. An investor is assumed to estimate the mean return and variance of return for each asset being considered for the portfolio over the single period. we will concentrate on mean variance portfolio theory. mean variance theory has remained the cornerstone of modern portfolio theory despite these alternatives. risk measures such as beta. . Borrowing a concept from the next section. 1977. Papers by Fama (1970). Nevertheless. 1965. the multi-period problem can be solved as a sequence of single- 3 The appropriate length of the period in a single-period solution is a topic of signi®cance on which very little research has been done. 3 In addition. 1976) o€ered alternative portfolio theories that included more moments such as skewness or were accurate for more realistic descriptions of the distribution of return (Fama. the implications of mean variance portfolio theory are well developed. of course. and there is no evidence that adding additional moments improves the desirability of the portfolio selected. Professionals who have never run an optimizer have learned that correlations as well as means and variances are necessary to understand the impact of adding a security to a portfolio. 1974). First. Elton. researchers (see Lee. add information and are recognized and used by investors who have no idea of the theory behind them. One of the major theoretical problems that has been analyzed is how the single-period problem should be modi®ed if the investor's true problem is multi-period in nature.J. 1974) and Merton (1990). these estimates are for the single decision period. 1958). Rather. Once again. mean variance theory itself places large data requirements on the investor. Gruber / Journal of Banking & Finance 21 (1997) 1743±1759 1745 portfolio that had the same expected return and less risk than a portfolio constructed by ignoring the interactions between securities. widely known. The precepts of mean variance theory work. Early work developed necessary conditions on either the utility function of investors or the return distribution of assets that would result in mean variance theory being optimal (see. M. we believe there are two reasons for its persistence. and Mossin (1969) have all analyzed this problem under various assumptions. a simpli®cation relative to including additional moments that might more completely describe the distribution of returns of the portfolio. Hakansson (1970. In addition. for example. Tobin. Thus.E. and have great intuitive appeal. Mean variance portfolio theory was developed to ®nd the optimum portfolio when an investor is concerned with return distributions over a single period. The papers found that under several sets of reasonable assumptions.J. the correlations or covariances between all pairs of assets being considered need to be estimated. Kraus and Litzenberger. Elton and Gruber. J. M. it leads to a mutual fund theorem. one made up of the riskless asset and one representing the tangency portfolio. First. There are two other types of theoretical research that have received substantial attention in the literature but have not had a major impact on the . and this di€ers from the utility function that is appropriate for decision-making over a single period. A major research topic for the future will be how this empirical literature should e€ect optimum multi-period portfolio decisions. Another strand of theoretical research has been the study of separation theorems. four funds are needed. mutual fund theorems provide guidance with respect to which types of commingled funds to o€er. and we will discuss it again in later sections. There has been a substantial amount of research in the last decade showing that mean returns and variances are related over time and are functions of easily observable variables (Fama and French. 1988). the optimum portfolio would be di€erent from that selected if only one period was examined. Elton. a reconciliation between theory and the actual array of mutual funds which exist would be useful. for ®nancial institutions such as banks or insurance companies. Two of the portfolios are any two portfolios of risky assets that lie on the ecient frontier and the remaining two portfolios are the instruments which yield the riskless lending and borrowing rates. The tangency portfolio is the portfolio that maximizes the ratio of expected return minus the return on the riskless asset to the standard deviation. One assumption underlying most multi-period portfolio analysis is independence of returns between periods. it facilitates calculation in that the portfolio problem can be stated as ®nding the tangency portfolio to a ray passing through the riskless asset in expected return standard deviation space. The di€erence arises because the appropriate utility function in the multi-period case is a derived utility function that takes into account multiple periods. As the assumption of a constant riskless lending and borrowing rate is relaxed. One of the areas of theoretical research deals with how many mutual funds are needed and what is the nature of the portfolios that comprise them under alterative assumptions about the nature of asset returns or utility functions (see for example Ross. While a substantial amount of work has been undertaken on mutual fund separation. Gruber / Journal of Banking & Finance 21 (1997) 1743±1759 period problems. if there are di€erent riskless lending and borrowing rates but short sales of risky assets are allowed. the choice of the optimum portfolio of risky assets is unequivocal and independent of the investor's taste for expected return or variance. Campbell and Shiller. namely that all investors can obtain their desired portfolio by mixing two mutual funds. more still needs to be done. It is easy to show that if an investor has access to a riskless asset. 1989. more funds and new types of funds enter the decision set.1746 E. In particular. For example.J. other assumptions. Second. This is the separation theorem. However. Furthermore. It has three implications. 1978). This is important because it provides guidance to investors and the mutual fund industry on what kinds of portfolios should be attractive. 1979). 1983). This ranking device clari®ed the characteristics of securities that would lead to their inclusion in an optimum portfolio. 1978a. The con®rmation in some cases assumes a somewhat more realistic set of assumptions such as lognormal rather than normal returns and more general utility functions. However. With the enormous improvement in computer speed and memory. this analysis. the portfolio problem and consumption investment problem are solved simultaneously. (1976. This solution clari®es why a security enters into the optimum portfolio and provides a simple ranking device that allows easy solution. These have suggested ways of speeding up the computations and incorporating more realistic short sales assumptions. In the single-index case.J. early computational concerns about solving large-scale problems have disappeared. The basic insight that made the EG&P algorithms work is the following: most analysts who solve portfolio problems use a model to estimate the covariances between securities. the ranking is by the excess return (expected return minus riskless rate) divided by the security's beta. What still has value is the insights into the composition of the optimum portfolio that can be obtained by simple solutions to the portfolio problem. Portfolio problems can be solved by inverting a matrix. The other type of theoretical research that has received some attention is attempts to understand how current holdings and transaction costs should a€ect portfolio rebalancing. In the continuous-time formulation. Elton. but the results constitute in large part a con®rmation of standard discrete-time results. The primary result of the continuous-time framework has been to con®rm the discrete-time results.E. has had little impact on practice. If the covariance is estimated by assuming that the correlation among securities is constant.J. First. the ranking is by excess return to standard deviation of return. In a series of papers. 1990). The major exception is Merton's results concerning hedging portfolios.. Again. Elton et al. EG&P have done some of the analysis (see Elton et al. Often the structure of the model used to estimate the covariances is such that the covariance matrix can be explicitly inverted and a closed form solution written down. a number of articles have been written that analyze the portfolio problem in continuous time (see Merton. M. Similar ranking devices exist for more complicated assumptions about how the covariance is estimated. Merton ®nds that in the intertemporal continuous-time framework an investor needs to hold hedging portfolios to protect against changes in the state variables. and have led to improved understanding of the e€ect of estimation error on optimum portfolios (see Chen and Brown. b) showed how optimum portfolios could be selected by a simple ranking device. while interesting. they made some simplifying . 1977. An applied area of research that has been of concern is computational eciency. A useful extension would be to pursue the solution where multi-index models describe the return-generating process. 1977. A number of papers have elaborated on the original EG&P analysis. Gruber / Journal of Banking & Finance 21 (1997) 1743±1759 1747 implementation of portfolio management. A solution that is consistent with the types of models used today would be useful. the type of inputs needed were easier for analyst to understand. while consistent with models used at the time they derived their results. and eit is the unique risky return of security I in period t and has a mean of zero and variance r2 . Index models: The earliest index model that received wide attention was the single-index model. The ®nal area that has received a great deal of attention is estimation of the inputs to the portfolio selection problem. The only di€erence is in the estimates of correlations. This was ®rst discussed in Markowitz. 4 These models have found wide application beyond estimating covariance structures. the accuracy of the market model in estimating covariances was higher than direct estimation (see. estimates of correlation coecients (or alternatively covariances) were required. namely the estimation of the covariance or correlation structure. and in particular one variant of the single-index model. Index models and covariance estimates After mean variance portfolio theory was ®rst developed. We will not attempt to discuss all of this literature. for example. and are worth reviewing on their own. 3. Rmt the return on the market in period t. 4 . Furthermore. The market model is ‚it ˆ ai ‡ bi ‚mt ‡ eit Y where Rit is the return of stock I in period t. The use of multi-index return-generating models is standard in today's investment community. Finally. The principal tool developed for estimating covariances was index models. ai the unique expected return of security I. ei From the point of view of portfolio inputs.J.J. A. It is to this discussion that we now turn. are less typical of models used today. M. Rather. there was an enormous amount of work on estimating inputs. the market model. Elton and Gruber. Elton. Gruber / Journal of Banking & Finance 21 (1997) 1743±1759 assumptions that. if subjective estimates are used or if subjective modi®cation of historical data is used. For the ®rst time in the literature of ®nancial economics. a steel an- Index models ®tted to historic data produce the same estimates of historic average returns and historic variance as do using the raw data itself. Even when using historical data to estimate the market model. and the accuracy of portfolio optimization was increased. bi the sensitivity of stock I to market movements.1748 E. but was developed and popularized by Sharpe (1967). 1973). we will concentrate on the literature that is unique to the portfolio selection area. the important characteristics of the use of the market model were that the number of estimates required was reduced. the reduced data requirements of the single-index model should lead to improved forecasting. Brown and Weinstein. in¯ation) (see Chen et al. 1993. The basic issue was what were the indexes and how many were there.. 1992). The alternative way to estimate a multi-index model was to pre-specify a structure. 5. 1967). 2. A large number of ®rms were started whose principal business was estimating betas. since betas are additive. The prototype multi-index model is ‚it ˆ ai ‡ t ˆ bij sjt ‡ eit Y jˆ1 i ˆ 1Y F F F Y x Y where bij is sensitivity of security I to index j. Statistical estimates of factors are likely to be used primarily to help con®rm that the pre-speci®ed indexes capture all of the major in¯uences and that they are important in explaining returns.. Although many of the estimates found their way into portfolio algorithms. Dhrymes et al. many ®nancial institutions estimate or use others' estimates of beta. 1980. an index of small minus large securities) (see Fama and French. J is the total number of indexes employed. and therefore is likely better able to meaningfully estimate betas than covariances. Ij the jth index. a number of researchers started to explore whether multi-index models better explained reality. 5 See Elton and Gruber (1995). ch. These ®rms developed sophisticated techniques that improved estimation over simply ®tting a regression to historical data. 1986). 5 In addition. production. 1984. The single-index model quickly took on a life well beyond its use in estimating inputs. Shortly after the market model was developed.. M. more commonly they were used to understand and manage the market exposure of the portfolio. Portfolios of traded securities (e. . and other terms as before. Market-plus-industry indexes (see Cohen and Pogue. Elton. security betas help a manager ascertain the impact of adding a security to the overall market exposure of the portfolio.J. 3.g. 1984).g. Surprises in basic economic indexes (e. In particular.. Indexes were extracted from the variance±covariance matrix of returns using either factor analysis or principal components analysis (see Roll and Ross. The use of models in which indexes are pre-speci®ed is gaining acceptance and is likely to be the dominant form of multi-index models in the future.J. Gruber / Journal of Banking & Finance 21 (1997) 1743±1759 1749 alyst can better understand the relationship between steel and the market than between steel and General Foods.E. Early work was primarily statistical in nature.. Three types of pre-speci®cations are used: 1. Cho et al. Currently. an additional dimension must be added for residual risk. the portfolio problem can be viewed as choosing among portfolios in multi-dimensional space with one dimension for expected return and an additional dimension for each beta. then the Elton et al. Portfolio analysis in a multi-index world: In the previous section we saw that single and multi-index models not only simplify the inputs to the portfolio selection problem. This use is discussed in the next section. Multi-index models also are useful in understanding and visualizing the portfolio choice. In the previous section we reviewed portfolio selection when the single-index model is employed. multi-index models are widely used in other ways. di€erent types of multi-index models have been used for di€erent applications. Elton. Finally. and this will likely continue in the future. Although this is equivalent to the mean variance problem. The analyst needs to have estimates of N times J betas and the variances of the J indexes. However. they also allow us to simplify the construction of the optimal portfolio. The same manager is likely to use a model expressed in terms of tradeable portfolios of securities when evaluating performance. Multi-index models are the building blocks for arbitrage pricing theory. managers may relate better to this choice. If we accept index models as a sucient description of reality. A manager interested in understanding the sensitivity of the portfolio to basic economic in¯uences needs a multi-index model that captures these in¯uences. multi-index models are the basic tool for evaluating fund managers. When some securities are mispriced. In particular. multi-index models can be used to reformulate mean-variance portfolio theory in a way that may be more meaningful to managers. (1976) solution reduces to the Treynor and Black (1973) solution that the investment in any stock should be proportional to the ratio of alpha to the variance of residual risk. The reformulation of the portfolio problem for multi-index models was ®rst analyzed by Ross (1978) and Ingersoll (1987). When returns are generated by a multi-index model. As shown in a later section. M. and may use a market-plus-industry model in deciding on sector rotation. If we make the additional assumption that the Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) holds and we ignore insight of Fama (1968) that the residuals from the market model cannot be uncorrelated and we allow short sales. Gruber / Journal of Banking & Finance 21 (1997) 1743±1759 Multi-index models can be used to provide inputs for a portfolio optimization technique.J. as with single-index models. This is the topic to which we now turn. B. a manager may ®nd it easier to think in terms of choosing exposures to risks and how much residual risk they will accept rather than total .J.1750 E. they also can lead to better forecasts and make the selection process easier to comprehend. Multi-index models are also used by portfolio managers to understand the sensitivity of the portfolio to various economic in¯uences and to allow the manager to make active bets on how the indexes will change in the next period. At the other extreme. While Fama's results are analogous to those presented above. 7 Fama (1996) develops models of equilibrium and portfolio optimization in the world of Merton's Intertemporal CAPM. or that will have the same cash ¯ows as. a set of liabilities has been treated in great detail in the literature of ®nancial economics. 4. the multi-period nature of the problem requires the addition of one more portfolio. The ®rst idea assumes that the user is interested in a minimum variance solution. If we assume that the coviarance between residuals is equal to zero. 6 They show that in this case each investor can form an optimum portfolio by choosing from among an investment in the riskless asset plus a number of portfolios equal to the number of indexes generating returns plus one. At one extreme. While conceptually easy to solve.J. The idea of simply holding a set of bonds that has the same duration as. liabilities have been treated in the immunization literature. to be included in the set of portfolio choices given to the investor. Elton. Gruber / Journal of Banking & Finance 21 (1997) 1743±1759 1751 risk. when they are tradeable portfolios). Elton and Gruber (1992b) prove that the optimum proportions in the portfolio of mispriced securities are proportional to the product of the inverse of the variance±covariance matrix of residuals and the vector of alphas. 7 This solution reduces to that presented by Ross (1978) and Ingersoll (1987) when indexes can be replicated perfectly (e.g. The general case where indexes cannot be exactly replicated (e. The solution involves forming one replicating portfolio for each index (simple rules are presented for forming those portfolios) plus one portfolio which is made up of mispriced securities. they may be macroeconomic in¯uences). Neither takes into 6 When indexes cannot be replicated exactly. the idea of simply treating liabilities as assets with negative cash ¯ows and constraining them to be present in the QPS solution to a portfolio optimization problem has been proposed.E.. the implementation of a system to include both liabilities and assets in a manner that produces real insight is much more dicult. there is no mathematical inconsistency in assuming residuals from the model are not correlated. the market portfolio. .g.J. M. Portfolio optimization with investor liabilities We believe that one of the important future directions for portfolio theory involves the explicit inclusion of liabilities into the asset allocation decision.. where securities exist which are priced out of equilibrium and indexes are not necessarily normally distributed. is analyzed by Elton and Gruber (1992b). this reduces to the ratio of each alpha to the variance of each residual risk. The second provides little insight into what is of necessity a problem with a multi-period time dimension. why bother with portfolio management models at all? Concern with portfolio performance predates the advent of modern portfolio theory. the Treynor ratio (Treynor. Portfolio evaluation Up to this point we have been concerned with how to construct an optimal portfolio. where both assets and liabilities are related to a one-index model. It was not long after Markowitz's path-breaking contribution that techniques were developed and applied (primarily to mutual fund data) for evaluating performance based on risk and return. Early studies employed a variety of evaluation techniques. it is only by employing evaluation measures that we can ®nd whether the combination of portfolio management techniques and the type of data used add value. the alpha of Jensen (1968.J. Elton. Gruber / Journal of Banking & Finance 21 (1997) 1743±1759 consideration the fact that cash ¯ows from liabilities are uncertain and subject to systematic risks which are similar to those for asset returns. Not only do evaluation models follow naturally from the theories of portfolio management. The special role of duration and cash ¯ow matching is developed and the analysis shows robust conditions under which cash ¯ow matching some. One of the early interesting studies on performance evaluation was published by Cowles (1933). We believe that the extension of this analysis employing a multi-index framework has great potential. These included the Sharpe ratio (Sharpe. It would be inappropriate to end this review article without a discussion of portfolio evaluation. What modern theory has taught us is that we need to be concerned with risk as well as return in examining performance.1752 E. 1969). 1965). but not all. and develop an equilibrium model and a portfolio theory where equilibrium exists but some assets are out of equilibrium. We have also discussed the fact that the payo€ from portfolio management models is in large part a function of the type and quality of the data used. of the liabilities is desirable. Elton and Gruber (1992a. 1966). Liabilities are usually not certain. but often depend on in¯uences such as in¯ation and changes in interest rates. b) formulate the asset liability problem. In this study he compared the average performance of a set of managed portfolios to a passive portfolio and concluded that the managed portfolios underperformed the passive benchmark. Similar in¯uences a€ect the return in assets. M. 5. If managers cannot add value to passive portfolios. solutions to the portfolio problem can be reached that allow investors to make tradeo€s in terms of not only expected return and total risk but in terms of the type of risk to which they will be exposed. By formulating both liabilities and asset returns as a function of indexes which a€ect these returns (and in the case of liabilities a€ect the amounts). the use of randomly generated passive portfolios of . Cowles examined return but ignored any consideration of risk.J. If the index is not ecient.J. evaluated a managed portfolio against randomly generated unmanaged portfolios of the same risk. The eciency of the index is of key importance.) as the correct measure. Relying on the defense that alpha simply represents the abnormal return over holding the portfolio of an index fund (e. Rpt the riskless rate in period t. Rmt the return on the reference portfolio. A. then performance attributed to any fund becomes a function of the particular index selected.. Each of these studies evaluated performance adjusting for a measure of risk.) used beta as the correct measure of risk. and e€t is the mean zero random error. and Friend et al. Gruber / Journal of Banking & Finance 21 (1997) 1743±1759 1753 the same risk of Friend et al. Some used total risk (Sharpe.E. each of the other authors used the fact that combinations of any portfolio and the riskless asset lie along a straight line in either expected return beta space or expected return standard deviation space to evaluate performance. While Friend et al. ch. Jensen's alpha is the intercept from the following time series regression: ‚€t À ‚pt ˆ ap ‡ bp …‚mt À ‚pt † ‡ e€t Y where Rpt is the return on the portfolio being evaluated at time t.J. M. the S&P 500 Index) and Treasury bills with the same beta also fails because it ignores the choices available to the manager. 8 Instead. for example. Since the investor is free to place some money in an index fund and some in riskless assets. Jensen's measure and benchmark identi®cation: The problem with identifying the correct index to use in the Jensen model has been discussed in detail in Roll (1978). Others (Treynor. bp the sensitivity to the reference portfolio.g. In the remainder of this article we will discuss some of the problems and progress that have occurred in employing the early models of portfolio performance. Because these measures are discussed in most books of portfolio management or investment analysis. Jensen. where the combination is selected to have the same risk as the managed portfolio. Alpha represents the return the manager earned over a combination of an index fund (the market portfolio) and Treasury bills. (1970). we will not review them in detail. . we will use Jensen's measure as a benchmark for further discussion. 24. small stocks (low market value stocks) have outperformed the S&P 500 Index for long periods of time. A small stock mutual fund manager with no selection ability or even negative selection ability would show superior performance during such 8 See. Elton. Elton and Gruber (1995). and Friend et al. For example. The alpha from this regression can be de®ned as the abnormal return above what would be earned if the CAPM held and thus the non-equilibrium return the manager earned. this is an appealing way to justify this model. There is a simpler and more intuitive explanation. Elton. a number of the funds had as their objective the construction of a portfolio of small stocks. On a theoretical and practical basis. it is clear that comparing active funds in total or a particular active fund to a passive strategy is inappropriate if these funds hold very di€erent types of securities from the passive portfolios with which they are being compared. Furthermore. It is easy to correct for small stocks by introducing another index into a Jensen-type model. in excess of 10% annually. mutual funds with higher expenses had at least as good performance as those with lower expenses. Thus. In the simplest case the model becomes ‚€t À ‚pt ˆ ap ‡ bp …‚mt À ‚ft † ‡ fssp …‚sst À ‚pt † ‡ ept Y where ‚sst is the return on an index of small stocks in period t and other terms as before. returning to viewing the manager relative to a passive fund or funds. In addition. A second defense for a multi-index model comes directly from arbitrage pricing theory. the average mutual fund had a large positive beta with the small stock index. using data for 1965±1984. In answer to Roll's critique. the results indicate that funds on average have negative alphas and funds which have higher expenses tend to do worse than funds with smaller expenses. Grinblatt and Titman.1754 E. multi-index versions of the Jensen measure are more appropriate than single-index versions. ®nally. Ippolito (1989). An examination of Ippolito's sample showed that funds in his sample had much more money in small stocks than that implied by the composition of the S&P 500 Index and the weighting of stocks in the S&P 500 Index. deviations from this linear function are a measure of a manager's selection ability. In fact. Gruber / Journal of Banking & Finance 21 (1997) 1743±1759 periods when compared to a combination of riskless assets and an S&P 500 index fund. 9 Thus.J. When this multi-index model is used to determine abnormal returns (a). which postulates that expected returns can be expressed as a linear function of sensitivities to more than one index. This is made very clear in a series of articles. Finally. (1993). and load funds underperform no-load funds. even after fees were deducted in computing performance and. 1987). found that a sample of mutual funds had positive alphas from the Jensen model. . the use of an appropriate model reversed the conclusions. load funds outperformed no-load funds. During the period studied by Ippolito. we know that if returns are generated by no more than N factors. This still leaves us with 9 See Elton et al. then N diversi®ed portfolios are sucient to describe relative returns and a linear combination of the N diversi®ed portfolios will be ecient (see Ross. 1978.J. The problems inherent in the use of a single-index model have led to the development of multi-index performance measures. small stocks had a much bigger return than large stocks. M. Connor and Korajzcyk. Elton et al. A second approach to developing multiple indexes is to ®nd portfolios of securities which span the types of investments held by mutual funds.J. This approach has been used by Sharpe (1992). and requires the betas to sum to one. Return ratio: Up to now we have been describing multi-index forms of Jensen's alpha as the appropriate measure to use for portfolio evaluation. Elton. B. Sharpe uses quadratic programming. the Sharpe measure becomes ap arsp . 10 The appropriate set of indexes to use to evaluate portfolio performance has not been completely resolved.. Elton et al. Elton et al. However.. since the weights are di€erent and this a€ects both ap and rep . Rather than measure the ratio of di€erence between average return on a portfolio and the riskless rate to the standard deviation of the portfolio as in the original Sharpe ratio. 1987. Several authors (e.g.J. (1996b) show that no more than ®ve indexes are sucient to explain the returns on domestic stock funds and suggest that performance can be meaningfully evaluated in terms of these ®ve easily identi®able indexes. (1993). In particular. a size-related index. In fact. Sharpe uses a 12-index model to explain the return on a broader set of mutual funds including domestic as well as international bond funds and stock funds. For example. ®ts the betas to minimize squared deviation from the regression plane. and a growth-value index to explain the return on domestic non-specialized mutual funds. 11 Sharpe uses QPS rather than regression analysis to identify di€erential return and risk. like regression analysis. but by using QPS. Sharpe's approach. and Blake et al.E. (1996a). a multi-index model) to the standard deviation of the di€erence. a bond index.g. the generalized ratio suggested by Sharpe uses the ratio of the di€erence between the average return on the portfolio and the benchmark portfolio (which can be a combination of several portfolios. 1991) have examined the use of multi-index models derived statistically to evaluate mutual fund performance. Lehmann and Modest. recent papers by Sharpe (1992) and Elton et al. . Elton et al. e. ®t their model via regression analysis. 11 While there are several ways to identify the benchmark portfolio and estimate sensitivities to it. M. He interprets the betas from these constrained regressions as being investment proportions. Sharpe (1994) has formalized a generalized version of the Sharpe ratio as a useful alternative for performance measurements in a multi-index world. (1996b) indicate that good models already exist. Gruber / Journal of Banking & Finance 21 (1997) 1743±1759 1755 the problem of which multi-index models to use. In a sense this is a return to our earlier section on multi-index models where we discussed alternative ways of specifying them. Sharpe introduced constraints so that the sum of the betas equals 1 and no beta is negative. if this is done via a time series analysis of a multi-index model. The results from this estimation will be somewhat di€erent. 10 Another advantage of using these models is that the measured betas indicate the type of securities each fund is holding. (1996a) employ a four-index model involving the S&P 500 Index. g.and threeyear periods. D. However. Four recent studies have found persistence in mutual fund performance: Hendricks et al. Both Sharpe (1994) and Elton et al. The last two studies use multi-index models based on portfolios of securities. The general conclusion is that timing does not increase risk-adjusted returns and may even lower them. (1996a) show that alphas are more predictable if funds for which the model has low correlation (‚2 ` 0X80) during the ®t period are eliminated. Past performance when risk adjustment is done carefully through the use of an appropriately designed multi-index model allows investors to select funds that have superior future performance. This does not seem to be the case for most funds. ep 12 .J. However. and Elton et al.1756 E. Grinblatt and Titman (1992). 1984) that examine the reasonableness of this assumption. Lehmann and Modest. (1996a). Henriksson. Timing: The use of a single or multiple index model to judge performance and to forecast performance assumes that betas (sensitivities) are reasonably constant and that management does not change them to gain added return through market timing. Gruber / Journal of Banking & Finance 21 (1997) 1743±1759 Notice that both the multi-index Sharpe measure and a multi-index version of the Jensen measure will identify the same funds as having superior performance. This does suggest that these funds for which the model does not ®t well. Forecasting: We have examined some alternative measures of performance. then performance evaluation is of no help when selecting a fund or a manager. Elton. Elton et al. (1996a) document that the top 10% of funds ranked on past alpha over a one. the subsequent alpha is signi®cantly increased. 1966. The more immediate question for this article is whether changing betas cause the betas on multi-index models to be so unreliable as to be of no value.. they produce positive alphas in a period when alphas are negative for the fund industry as a whole. Treynor and Mazuy. but we have not yet faced an important issue. Large changes in the portfolio betas in the multi-index model would cause betas to be poorly estimated and should cause past alphas to be unrelated to future alphas. Finally. 12 C. The answer appears to be ``no''. when modern portfolio theory is followed and funds are weighted proportionally in the top decile by ap ar2 rather sp than equally weighted. (1993). Sharpe (1994). There are a number of papers (e. If past performance is unrelated to future performance.J. Elton et al. they can rank funds in di€erent order.and three-year period not only provide superior risk-adjusted return in future one. M. which may include funds attempt- It is worth noting that Elton and Gruber (1992b) show that under reasonable sets of assumptions the optimal amount to invest in an actively managed fund in an actively managed portfolio of funds is proportional to ap ar2 . The major purpose in analyzing past performance is to gain insight into the future. (1996a) ®nd that past alphas have some predictive power. 1987. Cohen. E. Gruber / Journal of Banking & Finance 21 (1997) 1743±1759 1757 ing to time the market.. E. R. 386±403. Pogue. Campbell. Elton. Elton. we suspect. we would expect to ®nd persistence in performance. Cho.. if superior management exists.. then unless this performance is re¯ected in higher fees. Gruber. Weinstein. 1993.E..R. R. J. S. we want to discuss why we bother with performance. The fact that performance shows persistence suggests that at least some managers have superior information and give us hope that modern portfolio theory can be used to bene®t the investor. Gruber. 1993. 166±193. Final comments: In this article we have attempted to review modern portfolio theory and to highlight some topics and areas of future research. An empirical evaluation of alternative portfolio selection models. The facts that mutual funds (and. D.. E. 1986. 1±10. 195±228. Journal of Finance. In a perfectly ecient market we would expect performance to be random over time. A new approach to testing asset pricing models: the bilinear paradigm. it should be re¯ected in persistence in performance. M. Elton. Estimation risk and simple rules for optimal portfolio selection.. References Blake.J.. While some funds might outperform an appropriate passive strategy and others underperform it. if superior management exists. Ross. Brown. N. S. The performance of bond mutual funds. We apologize to the authors of the hundreds of interesting papers in portfolio theory that we have not cited in this paper.C. Because of contraints on time and space.J.. 1983. Journal of Business 46. 1988. C.J.J.Y. On the other hand.. 1967. Chen. 1984. M. The dividend-price ratio and expectations of future dividends and discount factors. Journal of Business 59.. Chen.. On the robustness of the Roll and Ross arbitrage pricing theory. we have not included references to many areas of interesting research. should be examined separately and are worthy of further study. Journal of Finance 38... Journal of Business 66 (3). S.J. Acknowledgements The authors would like to thank Giorgio Szeg for helpful comments on an o earlier version of this paper. 371±403. Review of Financial Studies 1 (3). K.J.. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 19 (1). Shiller. 1087±1093. the di€erence would be strictly random over time. S. Why bother with performance? In closing this section. Brown... . J. M. Economic forces and the stock market. Roll. managers in general) do not raise fees to re¯ect performance and that fees as a percent of assets tend to be lower for good performing funds mean that. Elton.J.. 329±345.F. G. Gruber. S. A. 1987. E. Fama. Gruber.. E. Mutual Funds and Other Institutional Investors.S. American Economics Review 60. Journal of Finance 13 (1). E. The relation between mean-variance eciency and arbitrage pricing.. I. In: Jarrow et al. 163±174. Elton. Gruber. M. Portfolio analysis with a non-normal multi-index return generating prices.. M. M. Multifactor portfolio eciency and multi-factor asset pricing. Blume. 23±49.. Korajzcyk. Gruber. S. Padberg. Gruber. 98±112. Journal of Business 69... 1995..W....J. Hlavka. McGraw-Hill. 427±465.W.J. K. 1996a. 1970. 1992. 1977.. Friend.. Blake.. New York University. M. 1984.. Fama.R. 1989. S....F.. French. M. Gruber. Journal of Business 60. Elton. 1±22. Journal of Finance 39 (2). E. A. E. The persistence of risk-adjusted mutual fund performance.. Simple criteria for optimal portfolio selection. Portfolio theory when investment relatives are lognormally distributed. I. Journal of Financial Economics 25 (1).J. 296±302.J. Journal of Finance 47. Elton.J. Fama... mutual funds. Constantinides. M. 323±346. 1933. 5±16. 1970. Simple criteria for optimal portfolio selection with upper bonds. Elton. Simple criteria for optimal portfolio selection: the multi-index case.F.F.. E.. E.. E.. 1968. Modern Portfolio Theory and Investment Analysis.. M. Elton.R.J. Elton. 5±26. Elsevier. 1977±1984. Gruber. 409±419. M. M. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 31. Grinblatt.J.. 1203±1232. Padberg. 1974.. Fama. The cross-section of expected stock returns. (Eds.. 441±465. Eciency with costly information: a reinterpretation of evidence from managed portfolios.. Malliaris. 206±214. .. 9. 1992a.J. Journal of Finance 11 (5). 1993. Gruber. C. Can stock market forecasters forecast? Econometrica 1 (3)..J. Journal of Finance 47. M. Journal of Banking and Finance 16.J.. E. N. E. M. Gruber. Simple rules for optimal portfolio selection: the multi group case. Elton. 1992b.B. E..J. Grinblatt.J.F.J. M. 1978a. Optimal investment strategies with investor liabilities. The persistence of mutual fund performance. C.. French. M.. Gruber. 1992. P. 5th ed. New York..J. Journal of Finance 8 (5). Journal of Finance 29...J.. Operation Research.J. Elton. 153±157. Elton. Das.. Elton. M.. E. Padberg. Review of Financial Studies 6 (1). 1965. Handbooks in O. G. In: Elton. Dhrymes.. E. Amsterdam.J.J. E. Gruber / Journal of Banking & Finance 21 (1997) 1743±1759 Connor.. M.. E.. M. M. M.1758 E. Management Science 11. Amsterdam. Friend. E. Gruber.J. Gruber.W. Titman. 1991.J. New York. 1973. E. Portfolio analysis in a stable Paretian market. Common factors in mutual fund returns. Journal of Finance 23 (1).R. E. 1265±1273. M. M. Portfolio theory.. behavior and performance of U.).J. K. Padberg. M. Elton.. Wiley. Elton. Risk return and equilibrium: some clarifying comments. Padberg.J..R. Crockett.J. Simple criteria for optimal portfolio selection: tracing out the ecient frontier.J. J. Cowles. A critical reexamination of the empirical evidence on the arbitrage pricing theory.). Gruber. Gruber (Eds. 97±112. Unpublished working paper..R.S.J. Blake.. Gultekin.J. 1996. Multiperiod consumption-investment decisions. Business conditions and expected returns on stocks and bonds. 29±40.F. R.. Fama. Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting 1.. 1996b.. 1978b. and N. 1341±1357. Estimating the dependence structure of share prices ± implications for portfolio selection. vol. M. 1979. E..J. M. The attributes.W.. Titman.. 1976. Portfolio Theory: 25 Years Later. Elton. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 12 (3). 1995.W. Fama. North-Holland..J. Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting 2 (1). New York.. Wiley. New York. Journal of Business 42 (2)... Journal of Finance 23 (2). F. 1992.. Journal of Finance 48.. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 12. 277±293. Review of Economic Studies 25. Oxford. 1987. and the evaluation of investment portfolios. Theory of Financial Decision Making. Patel. 167±247. 1952.. 1051±1069. 49±57. the pricing of capital assets. 1965. 1994. D. J. skewness e€ect and the risk return relationship. 1968. Journal of Finance 35 (5). 1969. Amsterdam. Functional form.... Harvard Business Review 43. 1085±1100. Eciency with costly information: a study of mutual fund performance. Management Science 13. A simpli®ed model of portfolio analysis.. 389±415. Journal of Finance 7. R. Sharpe. J. Quarterly Journal of Economics 104. J. N. 1958. Ingersoll. Gruber / Journal of Banking & Finance 21 (1997) 1743±1759 1759 Hakansson. Risk. Optimal multiperiod portfolio policies...F.. C. 223±265.. Portfolio Theory with Applications to Bank Asset Management. Portfolio selection. o New York. Henriksson. 93±130. Mazuy. How to rate management of investment funds. Kraus. Mossin. Mutual fund performance evaluation: a comparison of benchmarks and benchmark comparisons. Jensen. R. 1980. Journal of Business 39. Szeg. 1974±1988. Huang. 1073±1103. Optimal investment and consumption strategies under risk for a class of utility functions. W. 77±91.C. 254±286.. Merton.. Journal of Portfolio Management. Mutual fund performance. 587±607. 119±138. Journal of Finance 42. S... Sharpe. Asset allocation: management style and performance measurement. K. Econometrica 38.. Hot hands in mutual funds: the persistence of performance. How to use security analysis to improve portfolio selection. Sharpe. J..E.. Lehmann.. R.M. H. The Netherlands. S.. Ippolito. Basil Blackwell. 1989. Treynor. Foundations for Financial Economics. 1977. B. J. Markowitz.J. 66±86.J... J. The Sharpe ratio. R. 1993. Litzenberger. R. 1978. 215±229. 19651984... M. 1959. 201±224. W. 1973. Ross. M. The performance of mutual funds in the period 1945-1964. 1966. 1970. 1±23. 73±96. Jensen. Rowman and Little®eld. Modest. Journal of Finance 21 (4). C. J. R. 1967. Journal of Business 46. H. N. 7±19. 1969.. Academic Press. 63± 75.. A. 1984. 1988... Treynor. Black. Hendricks. 1980.. Sharpe. 1978. An empirical investigation of the arbitrage pricing theory. Continuous Time Finance. Ambiguity when performance is measured by the securities market line. D. Tobin. 1966. W. Market timing and mutual fund performance. Liquidity preference as behavior toward risk. Journal of Economic Theory 17. Hakansson. 1976. Mutual fund separation in ®nancial theory ± The separation distributions. Markowitz. 131±136. 55. M. Convergence in multiperiod portfolio choice. Ross. Journal of Business 41. . W.. Roll.. Journal of Business 57.A. 1990. Elton. Journal of Finance 33.. Treynor. Skewness preference and the valuation of risky assets. R. 65± 86. R. Journal of Financial Economics 1. North-Holland. Lee. Litzenberger. G. Journal of Portfolio Management 18. Roll. Zeckhauser. Can mutual funds outguess the market? Harvard Business Review 44. Portfolio Selection: Ecient Diversi®cation of Investments. 1974. 1987..
Copyright © 2024 DOKUMEN.SITE Inc.